Uncertain link between financial regulators, outcomes

By Howard Davies
0 Comment(s)Print E-mail Shanghai Daily, March 13, 2013
Adjust font size:

In?the early phases of the financial crisis, it was fashionable to argue that the United States' system of regulation needed a fundamental structural overhaul.

Differences of opinion between the Securities and Exchange Commission (SEC) and the Commodity Futures Trading Commission (CFTC) had obstructed effective oversight of investment banks and derivatives trading (only the US believes that it makes sense to regulate securities and derivatives separately).

Indeed, the plethora of separate banking regulators had created opportunities for banks to arbitrage the system in search of a more indulgent approach to capital.

Likewise, the lack of a federal insurance regulator had left AIG regulated by the Office of Thrift Supervision (OTS) and the New York State Insurance Department, which proved to be a wholly inadequate arrangement.

Little has come of these arguments. The Dodd-Frank Act did succeed in putting the OTS out of its misery, but jealous congressional oversight committees have prevented a merger of the SEC and CFTC, and nothing has been done to rationalize banking supervision. So the American system looks remarkably similar to the one that turned a collective blind eye to the rise of fatal tensions in the early 2000s.

One factor that contributed to institutional stasis was the absence of a persuasive alternative.

In the decade or so leading up to the meltdown of 2007-2008, the global trend was toward regulatory integration. Almost 40 countries had introduced single regulators.

The movement began in Scandinavia in the early 1990s, but the most dramatic change came in 1997, when the United Kingdom introduced its Financial Services Authority (I was its first chairman).

One-stop shop

There were economies of scale and scope, and financial firms typically like the idea of a one-stop (or, at worst, a two-stop) shop.

A single regulator might be expected to develop a more coherent view of trends in the financial sector as a whole.

Unfortunately, these benefits did not materialize, or at least not everywhere. It is hard to argue that the British system performed any more effectively than the American, so the single-regulator movement has suffered reputational damage.

The truth is that it is hard to identify any correlation between regulatory structure and success in heading off or responding to the financial crisis. Among the single-regulator countries, Singapore and the Scandinavians were successful in dodging most of the fatal bullets, while the UK evidently was not.

Does it matter whether the central bank is directly involved?

Many central bankers maintain that the central bank is uniquely placed to deal with systemic risks, and that it is essential to carry out monetary and financial policies in the same institution. Again, it is hard to find strong empirical support for that argument.

The Dutch and American central banks, with direct oversight of their banking systems, were no more effective in identifying potentially dangerous systemic issues than were non-central bank regulators elsewhere. Canada is often cited as a country that steered its banks away from trouble, even though they sit uncomfortably close to US markets. But the Bank of Canada is not now, and has never been, a hands-on institutional supervisor.

So perhaps the US Congress has been right to conclude that changing the structure of regulatory bodies is less important than getting the content of regulation right.

It is difficult now to discern a coherent pattern. Certainly, the trend toward full-service single regulators outside the central bank has slowed to a crawl (though Indonesia is consolidating regulators at present).

There is no consensus on the role of the central bank: in around a third of countries, it is the dominant player, in another third it has responsibilities for banks only, while in the remaining third it is a system overseer only. We could see this as a controlled experiment to try to identify a preferred model.

After all, financial systems are not so different from one another. But there is no sign of a considered assessment being prepared, which might at least help countries to make better-informed choices, even if it did not conclude that one model was unambiguously best.

Howard Davies, former chairman of Britain's Financial Services Authority, deputy governor of the Bank of England, and director of the London School of Economics, is a professor at Sciences Po in Paris. Shanghai Daily condensed the article.

 

Print E-mail Bookmark and Share

Go to Forum >>0 Comment(s)

No comments.

Add your comments...

  • User Name Required
  • Your Comment
  • Enter the words you see:   
    Racist, abusive and off-topic comments may be removed by the moderator.
Send your storiesGet more from China.org.cnMobileRSSNewsletter
主站蜘蛛池模板: 久久九九久精品国产| 国产中文欧美日韩在线| 中文字幕在线看片| 激情图片视频小说| 国产在线视频一区二区三区98| www.亚洲精品| 最近中文字幕mv高清在线视频| 午夜精品一区二区三区在线观看| 影音先锋男人看片资源| 扒开双腿猛进湿润18p| 亚洲国产日韩在线| 精品黑人一区二区三区| 国产漂亮白嫩的美女| a√天堂中文在线最新版| 日本动漫黄观看免费网站| 亚洲日本人成中文字幕| 精品亚洲成a人无码成a在线观看| 国产女高清在线看免费观看| 999国产精品999久久久久久 | 日韩一区二紧身裤| 亚洲欧美日韩综合一区| 精品欧美军人同性videos| 国产日产精品系列推荐| 97香蕉久久夜色精品国产| 成人免费一区二区三区视频| 久久精品国产欧美日韩| 欧美精品亚洲精品日韩1818| 北条麻妃在线一区二区| 高清在线精品一区二区| 国产精品视频铁牛tv| 一二三四日本视频中文| 日本人强jizzjizz老| 亚洲av无码不卡在线播放| 热RE99久久6国产精品免费| 四虎网站1515hh四虎| 国产男女野战视频在线看| 国内精品区一区二区三| 中文乱码精品一区二区三区 | 台湾一级淫片完整版视频播放| 国产h片在线观看| 欧美精品hdvideosex|